Most economists see bubbles as market failures - irrational exuberance that misallocates resources and destroys value. William Janeway, the renowned venture capitalist and economic historian, sees something different: a powerful force for technological progress¹.
The Innovation Paradox
Here's the challenge that every research institute faces: the most important breakthroughs often look economically irrational at first. The transistor, recombinant DNA, quantum computing - none of these would have passed a traditional cost-benefit analysis in their early stages².
But somehow, they happened anyway. Why?
The Two Types of Bubbles
Economic historian Carlota Perez distinguishes between two fundamentally different types of bubbles³:
Mean-reversion bubbles
Where investors bet that current trends will continue indefinitely. Think housing bubbles or crypto speculation. These typically end in crashes that destroy value.
Installation bubbles
Where collective excitement about a fundamentally different future concentrates resources on otherwise "irrational" pursuits. These can actually accelerate progress.
The difference matters enormously.
While the 2008 financial crisis destroyed trillions in value, the 1990s tech bubble - despite its excesses - left behind the infrastructure and talent pool that built our modern digital economy⁴.
Perez's analysis of these "double bubbles" at technological turning points reveals how periods of intense speculation, despite their excesses, can play a crucial role in installing new technological infrastructure⁵.
How Productive Bubbles Work
Productive bubbles solve what economists call the "appropriability problem" in research⁶. When pursuing fundamental breakthroughs:
Bubbles of collective excitement can override these rational constraints. Consider three historical examples:
1. The Transistor Revolution
When Bell Labs began pursuing solid-state electronics in the 1940s, vacuum tubes were cheaper and more reliable. The research looked economically irrational. But wartime funding and postwar industrial optimism created a bubble of excitement that concentrated enough talent and resources to make transistors viable⁷.
2. The Biotech Wave
The early days of genetic engineering faced enormous technical uncertainty. But waves of excitement in the 1980s and 1990s funded hundreds of companies and experiments. Many failed, but the survivors transformed medicine⁸.
3. The Computer Revolution
The development of early computers required massive investment with unclear returns. But as documented by Nathan Rosenberg, the concentration of resources during this period created lasting technological capabilities⁹.
The Bubble Machine
The most powerful example might be Bell Labs itself. As Jon Gertner documents in "The Idea Factory"¹⁰, Bell Labs didn't just create innovations - it created an environment that made innovation more likely by:
It became what venture capitalist Marc Andreessen calls a "bubble machine"¹¹ - an environment that spawns productive bubbles across multiple fields.
Managing Bubble Dynamics
For research institutes, this suggests a counterintuitive approach to innovation:
1. Cultivate Productive Excitement
2. Enable Parallel Exploration
3. Build on Solid Foundations
The Evidence Base
The productive role of bubbles isn't just theory. Research supports it:
The Power of Productive Bubbles
The best innovation combines:
Your job isn't to avoid bubbles. It's to create and channel productive ones. To build environments where excitement about the future becomes a force that helps bring that future about.
Because sometimes the most rational approach to innovation is enabling productive "irrationality."
Enter The Arena
For research institutes, this means asking new questions:
Map Your Bubble Potential
Design Your Machine
Start Small But Think Big
References:
¹ Janeway, W. H. (2012). "Doing Capitalism in the Innovation Economy: Markets, Speculation and the State." Cambridge University Press.
² Arrow, K. (1962). "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention." In The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors, Princeton University Press.
³ Perez, C. (2002). "Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital: The Dynamics of Bubbles and Golden Ages." Edward Elgar Publishing.
⁴ O'Sullivan, M. (2007). "Funding New Industries: A Historical Perspective on the Financing Role of the U.S. Stock Market in the Twentieth Century." NBER Working Paper.
⁵ Perez, C. (2009). "The Double Bubble at the Turn of the Century: Technological Roots and Structural Implications." Cambridge Journal of Economics, 33(4), 779-805.
⁶ Arrow, K. (1962). "Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention." In The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity: Economic and Social Factors, Princeton University Press.
⁷ Riordan, M., & Hoddeson, L. (1997). "Crystal Fire: The Invention of the Transistor and the Birth of the Information Age." W.W. Norton & Company.
⁸ Pisano, G. P. (2006). "Science Business: The Promise, the Reality, and the Future of Biotech." Harvard Business Press.
⁹ Rosenberg, N. (1983). "Inside the Black Box: Technology and Economics." Cambridge University Press.
¹⁰ Gertner, J. (2012). "The Idea Factory: Bell Labs and the Great Age of American Innovation." Penguin Press.
¹¹ Andreessen, M. (2014). "Why Bitcoin Matters." New York Times.
¹² Saxenian, A. (1996). "Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route 128." Harvard University Press.
¹³ Lerner, J. (2009). "Boulevard of Broken Dreams: Why Public Efforts to Boost Entrepreneurship and Venture Capital Have Failed--and What to Do About It." Princeton University Press.
¹⁴ Perez, C. (2009). "Technological Revolutions and Financial Capital: The Dynamics of Bubbles and Golden Ages." Cambridge Journal of Economics.
Innovation Strategy & Training for Future-Ready Organisations
ABN: 62 166 764 987